See more coverage of this event on the main IISD ENB website

We have launched a new website to better share our reports of global environmental negotiations.

As well as current coverage of new negotiations, you can find our original reports from this event by clicking here.

Distr. GENERAL

CONVENTION ON

BIOLOGICAL DIVERSITY

UNEP/CBD/SBSTTA/2/13

9 July 1996

ORIGINAL: ENGLISH



SUBSIDIARY BODY ON SCIENTIFIC, TECHNICAL

AND TECHNOLOGICAL ADVICE

Second Meeting

Montreal, 2 to 6 September 1996

ECONOMIC VALUATION OF BIOLOGICAL DIVERSITY

Note by the Secretariat

1. Introduction

1. Decision II/11 of the second meeting of the Conference of the Parties (COP) requested the Executive Secretary to compile an annotated list of studies and other relevant information on the social and economic valuation of genetic resources, including the demand by industry for genetic resources. This decision also requested the Executive Secretary to further elaborate the survey of measures taken by governments to implement Article 15, including national interpretations of key terms used in that Article, with a view to completing the survey in time for circulation at the third meeting of the COP.

2. Item 12.1 of the provisional agenda for the third meeting of the COP (document UNEP/CBD/SBSTTA/2/Inf.10) indicates that this meeting may consider "the compilation of views of Parties on possible options for developing national legislative, administrative or policy measures to implement Article 15".

3. In response to the COP's intention to explore the ways and means of implementing Article 15, the SBSTTA, in its medium-term programme of work for 1995-1997 (document UNEP/CBD/COP/2/5, recommendation I/2), decided that it would consider the provision of scientific, technical and technological advice on the economic valuation of biological diversity and its components, in particular in relation to access to genetic resources.

4. To assist the SBSTTA in its consideration of this item, the Secretariat has prepared this Note on the economic valuation of biological diversity, with a particular emphasis on the valuation of genetic resources. The Note briefly recalls the need for the economic valuation of genetic resources within the Convention and then reviews the existing literature. The Note concludes with some observations about possible advice and recommendations that the SBSTTA may wish to consider under this item of the provisional agenda.

2. Background

5. Economic theory holds that in order for any resource to be properly managed, the cost of using the resource needs to reflect all the values that society places upon it, social and economic, including the costs of the external effects associated with exploiting, transforming and using the resource, together with the costs of future uses forgone. In economic parlance this means internalising the external benefits and costs, known as externalities, associated with using a resource. Failure to properly value resources means that incorrect signals are sent to decision-makers, conveying, in turn, misleading information about the resources' scarcity and thus providing inadequate incentives for the management, efficient utilisation and enhancement of living resources.

6. It is widely acknowledged that the current use of biological resources is both inefficient and inequitable due to the fact that there is a gap between the private and social values of biodiversity. There are many causes for this gap, such as: (a) ignorance or uncertainty over the social consequences of private actions; (b) a structure of rights that encourages people to ignore the known social consequences of their actions ("tragedy of the commons"); and (c) government policy that fails to correct externalities and can worsen things (policy failure). These market and policy failures are, according to economists, the main underlying causes of biodiversity loss (Perrings 1995).

7. Economists often describe the range of benefits that biodiversity provides as set in Table 1.

Table 1. Total Economic Value of biological resources.

USE VALUE
+
PASSIVE OR NON-USE VALUE(1)
DIRECT + VALUE
INDIRECT + VALUE
OPTION + VALUE
(QUASI + OPTION VALUE)
EXISTENCE VALUE
Provision of basic resources: food, medicine, construction materials, nutrients. Providing support for economic activity and human welfare, e.g. watershed protection, waste storage and recycling, maintenance of genetic diversity and erosion control. Providing basic resources: e.g. oxygen, water, genetic resources. Preservation of future direct and indirect use values
Non-consumptive uses: recreation Conservation of yet unknown future uses Forests as objects of intrinsic value, as a bequest, as a gift to others, as a responsibility (stewardship). Includes cultural, religious and heritage values.
Plant genetic resources Providing information benefits such as scientific knowledge.

Source: Pearce, D.W. 1990. An Economic Approach to Saving the Tropical Forests. LEEC Paper DP 90-06. IIED, London; and Perrings (ed.) 1995. The Economic Value of Biodiversity, in Heywood, V.H. 1995, Global Biodiversity Assessment, UNEP, Cambridge University Press, UK.

(1) Passive use or non-use value is the value that individuals place on biological resources that they do not intend to use, but would feel the "loss" of if they were to disappear. Notes: Direct Value refers to those benefits that can be observed being consumed, although their consumption might not yield a meaningful price that can be assigned to that benefit. Indirect Value refers to those benefits that are not observed being consumed, but that are known to be essential to the preservation and maintenance of ecosystems. Option Value is the value placed on securing the future consumption of goods and services yielding direct and indirect value. Quasi-Option Value is the value of learning about future benefits that would be precluded by development or irreversible change of the forests today. This takes into account the fact that current valuations are circumscribed by current knowledge of forest functions. Existence Value is that value placed on an environmental asset independent of its current or future "usage". This incorporates the innate value of the forest in situ.

8. In the case of biological diversity the value of the intangible benefits (indirect value; option value; quasi-option value and existence value) is significant. Valuation and methodologies for evaluating the benefits of biological diversity at the species and ecosystem level are rapidly evolving. A recent and relatively comprehensive assessment of this area is provided in the Global Biodiversity Assessment (Perrings 1995).

9. Contemporary understanding of the benefits of genetic diversity and the value of the benefits that genetic resources provide is not so well appreciated. This is due to two main reasons: (a) that it is the least-known level of biodiversity and consequently our understanding of the resources is poorer than for other manifestations of biodiversity; and (b) estimating the value of the benefits of genetic diversity poses many extra methodological difficulties compared with undertaking a similar exercise for other aspects of biodiversity. This arises because the principal direct economic value of genetic diversity is the information that it represents. Measuring this benefit, as with other intangible benefits, has always been problematic because what is required is not a calculation of an easily measured consumptive process, but the value of the information that the resource brings to the production process. As this will often be only one of many sources of information required to develop the process, and often not even the most important source, assessing the proportion attributable to the natural genetic resources is not straightforward. Thus, what is being measured in this process is not the market for herbal remedies, but the value of the contribution that a natural biochemical makes to developing a new drug or a new crop variety. As there is no well-established methodology for estimating this type of contribution, it is largely dependent upon the subjective values of those making the assessment. Work on estimating other benefits of the value of genetic diversity (such as its indirect, option and existence values) is almost non-existent.

10. The agricultural, pharmaceutical, and horticultural industries have always relied upon access to "new" genetic resources as a source of innovation. Recent developments in biotechnology are not only increasing demand in these traditional markets, but also opening up new applications and markets for genetic resources. For example, there is a rapidly increasing demand for genetic resources from exotic bacteria found in extreme environments, known as "extremophiles"; an issue considered in some detail in document UNEP/CBD/SBSTTA/2/15.

11. Due to the magnitude of the global benefits derived from the use of genetic resources, their internalisation provides an important opportunity for ensuring sustainable use, the equitable sharing of benefits and, ultimately, the conservation of biodiversity. The Convention recognises the importance of using genetic resources as a means of achieving its goals. Article 15 provides a legal basis by which countries can assert ownership and control over these resources and thereby begin to internalise the externalities that currently exist.

12. In order to effectively implement the Convention's provisions with regard to the use of genetic resources, it is imperative that a reasonably accurate and reliable method (or methods) of evaluating these benefits be developed. At the moment there is only anecdotal evidence that genetic resources are valuable on a global basis. It is by no means clear how much particular countries or communities benefit or lose under the current regime. Neither is it clear which countries stand to gain or lose if the current situation is changed. Determining this is important because the benefit flows of genetic resources are complex, interrelated and very international. For example, the high level of interdependence in crop development meant that some of the genes that made a significant contribution to the Green Revolution came from the natural genes found in developed countries (Kloppenburg 1988). If mechanisms were established to internalise this international externality then developing countries would be compensating developed countries.

13. More specifically, knowing or being able to measure the economic value of genetic diversity is vital in order to properly implement many important elements of the Convention. The experience to date has been that contractual arrangements, or what have been described as Access and Benefit Sharing (ABS) Agreements, between the provider of genetic resources and those wishing to use the genetic resource have been the most common mechanism for endeavouring to implement the principles of the Convention. In the absence of some reliable method for estimating the value of genetic resources, the price received by the provider is largely determined by market practice. Given the lack of experience and precedent in many of the markets for genetic resources, it is unlikely that the value these markets give to the resource will reflect the full value placed on it by society. The experience in other markets for primary or raw materials is that rarely, if ever, do the suppliers receive optimal value for the resource. Indeed, given the circumstances of most of these ABS Agreements, with a large multinational company on one side and an individual collector on the other, it is most likely that the price received by the collector will be significantly less than the optimal price required to send the right signals to managers of these resources.

14. In an effort to obtain a better return for genetic resources many providers have started to negotiate rights to royalties over future profits from any product that relies on genetic material. From the viewpoint of the provider, determining the optimal balance between the immediate return -- in the form of the up-front fee -- and the future return -- in the form of the rate of the royalty -- is not really possible without some understanding of the value of the genetic material. Even calculating what is a fair royalty is difficult without this basic type of information.

15. There are many other more fundamental questions surrounding the use of genetic resources and the implementation of the principles of the Convention that will rely to some extent on being able to understand the economic value of that use. Although the Convention provides that the benefits of the use of genetic resources be shared equitably, it provides little by way of specific detail as to how this is to be achieved. Guidance of some sort will be required to ensure that benefits are shared properly. Questions such as:

(i) What is "fair and equitable"?

(ii) What are the nature of such benefits?

(iii) What mixture of different benefits are appropriate for different uses of genetic resources?

(iv) How should benefits be shared?

(v) What type of mechanisms are to be preferred in identifying stakeholders and in channelling benefits back to local and indigenous peoples?

(vi) Who are the beneficiaries?

(vii) How should unidentified beneficiaries' or future generations' interests be taken into account?

(viii) How should retrospectivity be dealt with?

will all depend to some extent on being able to develop a reliable method for economically evaluating the benefits of genetic resources.

16. Controlling access to genetic resources has, in other fora, proven to be a controversial and divisive issue. This is due largely to differing expectations about the value of genetic resources. The absence of reliable facts and figures, or of a sound understanding of the economic value of genetic resources, has allowed rhetoric and politics to dominate the debate in some fora, making progress difficult. These tensions may well arise in any consideration that the Convention gives to the issue. Consequently, progress in implementing Article 15 may well be difficult without reliable information about the economic value of genetic resources.

17. Many other important provisions of the Convention are dependent upon a reliable methodology for estimating the value of genetic resources. For example:

1. Given the increasing preference for market-based policies around the world, integrating the conservation and sustainable use of biological diversity in relevant sectorial or cross-sectorial plans, programmes and policies will rely significantly on being able to assign an economic value to all aspects of biological diversity, including genetic resources;

2. Developing and implementing the requirements of the Convention with regard to environmental-impact assessment procedures will similarly depend on being able to assess the economic importance of genetic diversity.

3. Identifying the important components of biological diversity as required by Article 7 will be dependent on being able to measure the economic value not only of ecosystems and species, but also of genetic diversity. Indeed, Annex 1 of the Convention, which gives an indicative list of the important aspects of biological diversity, mentions several aspects that are heavily dependent on being able to make some assessment of the economic value of genetic diversity. For example, it specifically indicates that regard should be given to genomes and genes that are of economic value. It also mentions the species of medicinal, agricultural or other economic value that are of importance. Assessing whether a genome or species is of importance in these categories will manifestly depend on being able to measure the value of genetic diversity.

18. An ability to measure the value of genetic diversity is similarly important for properly: implementing Article 8(j), along with its sister provisions of Articles 10(c) and 18.4; understanding how intellectual property rights may have an influence on the implementation of the Convention as required by Article 16(5) and decision II/11 of the COP; implementing Article 19 on the handling of biotechnology and the distribution of its benefits; developing incentives in accordance with Article 11; and adopting measures that avert or minimise adverse impacts on biological diversity in accordance with Article 10(b), to name but a few. Without a more developed understanding of the values of genetic diversity, or the methodology to make such an evaluation, it is not only difficult to determine the right mechanisms for implementing the provisions of the Convention, but it might also lead to a situation where well-intentioned measures actually result in some developing countries being worse off than under the existing regime.

3. Biodiversity as an input into the research and development process

19. The major focus of the research carried out on the value of genetic resources has been on their use in the pharmaceutical and agricultural industries, which use genetic diversity as a source of information in their development of new products.

20. Economists have long analysed the research and development process as one of information utilisation, application and diffusion (Arrow 1962; Nordhaus 1969). The concept of research and development is usually presented as a production process itself dependent upon a stock of "information" for its generation of useful innovations (Stoneman 1983).

21. The information that genetic diversity represents may be brought into commercial use in one of three ways: the information contained in a genotype may be transferred to the desired end directly (i.e., through transferring genetic material), traditionally through breeding and hybridisation between closely related organisms, and more recently through novel technologies of gene transfer; the information can be exploited directly through the expressed phenotype of the organism, so that new organisms are brought directly into commercial production; and the information may be used to develop new products without translocating the biological material.

22. Pharmaceutical industries most often pursue the third of these means (making use of observed strategies in biological material), while agricultural industries most often pursue the first (Swanson 1995). For example, pharmaceutical companies screen diverse life forms in order to ascertain the presence of chemicals with biological activity (e.g. "alkaloids" in plants) (Fellows 1995). If this information is identified as having some useful potential, then the pharmaceutical industry will, within a laboratory environment, usually focus on the synthesis of that activity from basic chemical constituents (Albers-Schonberg 1995). On the other hand, agricultural and plant-breeding companies have, in the past, operated almost exclusively through the identification of useful traits within closely related organisms and the selective breeding for the transport of those genotypes into a particularly useful strain (Orians et. al. 1988). Although the two industries are pursuing the same basic object (i.e., the incorporation of successful biological strategies into the human economic system), they use contrasting techniques to effect this endeavour. Both industries make limited use of the second of these means -- the introduction of new organisms directly into the production process. This is also employed with some frequency by the horticultural industry.

23. The importance of biodiversity for these industries is that living systems must contain a library of such successful strategies. The manner in which such strategies are imported into production systems is not really crucial, except to the extent to which existing techniques limit the transferability of the information contained in biological diversity. At present, the technological frontier in this region of human industry is expanding rapidly, resulting in declining constraints on the transferability of this information. It is now possible to transfer strategies between organisms and living systems in ways that were not imaginable a few years ago. Consequently, the expansion of the technological frontier should dramatically increase, rather than reduce, the value of genetic diversity in the research and development process.

3.1 Empirical evidence of the value of genetic diversity in the pharmaceutical industry

24. The medicinal value of plants and their derivatives has been recognised for millennia. Traditional medicine has evolved by taking advantage of the genetic information in wild plants, selecting those that have developed characteristics that make them effective against human diseases. The informational value realised through the direct use of wild products is still very important in the developing world. It is estimated that some 80% of the people in the rural developing world rely chiefly on herbal medicines for their primary health care needs (Farnsworth and Soejarto 1991; Hamann 1988, both cited in Lewington 1993; Falconer 1990, for West Africa). These traditional systems typically rely on a wide range of species. In Chinese medicine alone, it is estimated that 80% of medications come from some 5,000 higher plants (Farnsworth and Soejarto 1991; Hussain 1991, cited in Lewington 1993). While these data do not indicate the relative importance of individual species, it is clear that traditional medicine relies on a wide diversity of natural products. Specific studies in Western Africa and Asia have identified between 70 and 200 plant species currently used by individual communities (Falconer 1990; Elliot and Brimacombe 1985, in Sayer 1991; Levy-Luxereau 1972, in WCMCe 1992). Worldwide, it is estimated that some 10,000 different species are used by at least one community for medicinal purposes (Fellows 1991 in Lewington 1993). Despite the apparent value in current applications of biological resources, estimating the importance and economic value of the biodiversity that gives rise to the possibility of more discoveries is a very recent field of interest.

25. In order to assess the value of biodiversity in the pharmaceutical industry, it is necessary to trace its input to the research and development process. A number of studies have recently been conducted that try to place a value on the genetic diversity in nature, based on the possibility of finding valuable information for the development of future pharmaceuticals. Table 1 presents a summary of these studies.

Table 1. Summary of the Literature on the Pharmaceutical Value of Biodiversity

Reference
Farnsworth and Soejarto (1985)
Principe (1989b)
McAllister (1991)
Principe (1989b)
Ruitenbeek (1989)
Harvard Business School
Pearce and Purosho-thaman (1992)
Simpson et al (1993)
Alyward (1993)
Fernandez (1994)
Reid et al (1993)
Biodiversity valued
plants
plants
trees
plants
Cameroonian species
Costa Rican species
rainforest plants
plants
plants
plants
biotic samples
Scope of values
US
OECD
global
OECD
not specified
not specified
OECD
not specified
US/Costa Rica
not specified
not specified
Type of data
drug sales
drug sales
drug sales
value of life saved
patent renewal costs
royalties on drug sales
drug sales and value of life saved
required net revenue from prospecting to create a land value of US$1/ha
net returns from prospecting
net return from prospecting for a single drug
royalties on drug sales
Type of value
annual
annual
annual
annual
annual
NPV
annual
NPV
NPV
NPV
NPV
Value per item (US$m)
200
200 US 600 OECD
0.25
37,500
7.5
0.253
1.95 - 350
197-19,887
40-459
40-459
not specified
Success rate for discovery of new drugs
1:250
1:2,000
3:100
1:5,000
not specified (10:500)
1:10,000
1:1,000 or 1:10,000
1:n+1 (4)
1:10,000
1:10,000
1:40,000
Value per untested species (1991 US$)
2,580,000
474,000
7,500
23,700,000
15-150
253
585-1,050,000
21 (1) 166 (2) 233 (3)
Industry will screen up to 29,040 if samples are free or 15,700 if US$50 per sample.
52-46,000,000

Expanded from Alyward (1993) incorporating the results of Simpson (1993) and Fernandez (1994). (1) per biotic sample in private cost scenario
(2) per species in social cost scenario
(3) per biotic samples royalty model
(4) n is the collection of species

26. There are, however, methodological problems with all of these studies. Vogel reviewed many of the studies referred to in Table 1 and concluded that even "the most comprehensive and thoughtful treatment" (Alyward 1993) was "so sensitive to a few key assumptions that the conclusions he [Alyward] reaches, 'the returns from pharmaceutical prospecting cannot be expected to generate a "market solution" to the biodiversity crisis', could easily be reversed". The key assumptions that Vogel identified were: the royalty rates chosen; the "hit rates" for bioactivity; the overall volume of biodiversity; and the diffusion of secondary compounds across habitats. Vogel applied the model developed by Alyward to estimate the value of Ecuador's genetic resources for use by the pharmaceutical industry and came up with a national value of $256 million. He then applied a series of quite plausible alternatives for each of the key assumptions used in Alyward's model and was able to come up with a figure of $429 billion. He observed, in an abstract of his book, that "[b]oth estimates teeter on a scaffolding of assumptions, all of which are defensible but may nevertheless turn out to be very wrong with hind sight. What will be the criterion of the Ecuadorian politician to decide. The bilateral $256 million or the multilateral $429 billion? The cynical answer is politics. For example, when timber interests are strong, the former will be cited as justification for the status quo, when environmental interests are strong the latter will be quoted long after the evidence has emerged to correct what turned out to be a false assumption".

27. Confirmation of Vogel's observations are found in the widely varying estimates given in the table of the economic value to the pharmaceutical industry of raw natural genetic material.

28. Even defining the extent of the contribution attributable to the information from naturally occurring genes has proven problematic in the literature. In a recent survey (Olsen et al. 1996), "Natural products research" (NPR) was found to be an important part of the research strategy of every pharmaceutical firm. For the large, vertically integrated firms, this typically amounts to 5% to 20% of the total research and development budget. About one-third of the firms taking part in the survey were small, specialised companies focused on collecting and screening; these firms expend a far greater proportion of their budgets on NPR, but it is a small part of total industrial expenditure. In this survey most companies stated that expenditure on NPR had recently been increasing.

29. The primary reason cited for the recent expansion of NPR activity was the declining cost of screening activities. The speed at which samples may be screened has increased by a factor of one hundred in the past decade, due to the efficient automation of screening techniques. Numbers of possible screenings now range from 300 plant species per year for a small specialist company, to hundreds of thousands of specimens (natural and synthesised) by a large generalist. Despite this development, other stages in research and development activities increase the cost of NPR, namely, the time and expense required to structurally elucidate the relevant portions of the molecule, i.e., to separate out and identify the precise chemical structures supplying the biological activity. This process was estimated to require, on average, 4 to 5 additional years to complete, and an additional $60,000 in development expenditure. Another more crucial factor discriminating against natural products was the critical necessity of an assured future supply. If the additional costs of natural-product development were to be undertaken (estimated at $200,000 in time and funds), then there must be a certainty of future flows of the resource required.

30. The asserted alternative to NPR was the modification of known active structures, and the screening of them once synthesised. These synthesised molecules were far more likely to be subject to massive levels of screening, as the cost of screening was low and the costs of subsequent development would be essentially zero (until clinical trials). In terms of sheer volume, synthesised molecules are the primary focus of research and development activity, but it is acknowledged throughout the industry that the templates for these compounds, and the vast numbers of permutations upon them, must always come from nature. Nature is the provider of complex active molecules, but these must be simplified in order to guarantee both understanding and future supplies.

31. It would therefore appear that virtually all research and development in the pharmaceutical industry has, to some extent, its source in naturally generated information. Confusion on this point emerges by reason of the specificity with which the industry has defined the term "Natural Products Research"; this term focuses on developing physical material within biological organisms directly into medicinal products (so-called "silver bullets"). Pharmaceutical companies usually disparage NPR for the expense of either: a) developing biological material into synthetic material; or b) procuring secure supplies of biological material across time. Given this narrowly defined role for natural products within the industry, it is not surprising that NPR is found to be only a minor portion of research and development.

32. It is very seldom that nature provides such a ready-packaged molecule, already purified and isolated for its impacts on the human species (although many pharmaceutical compounds now in use derive from about 40 such substances). More often, the value of biological material lies in its more generalised but equally fundamental information, which must then be further refined and developed. It seems that the vast majority of screened molecules are of this once-removed nature, derived from human modifications of natural templates. Literally hundreds of thousands of permutations may be built upon the foundation of a single template, and so synthesised substances are seen as being the focus of the screening industry. The fact remains that the raw material for this enterprise comes initially from natural templates. A proviso must be added in that there are some pharmaceutical companies that claim that it is now possible to produce wholly "rationally designed" pharmaceutical drugs. This is sometimes argued to represent a new independence from nature, although a complete shift to such products seems a remote possibility in the foreseeable future.

33. A wider understanding of what NPR entails leads to the conclusion that biological diversity is a crucial factor in the production of modern medicine, even though the industry itself recognises its contribution only in cases where it works most directly and completely. It appears that naturally generated information has had at least some role in the creation of virtually every pharmaceutical to date, and continues to provide the templates for current research.

3.2 Empirical evidence of the value of genetic diversity in agriculture

34. Plant breeders are constantly investigating the closest relatives of the small number of domesticated species to ascertain their potential for contributing to the productivity or resilience of the domestic varieties. This process of applying genetic techniques has had increasing application to and effects on the world's agricultural production. The Green Revolution, which brought a rapid increase in wheat and rice yields in developing countries, was fuelled by the use of improved seed varieties and the application of fertilisers and other chemical inputs. These have made high-yield crop varieties comparatively more profitable than other traditional grains and vegetables, and as a consequence the area sown with improved seed has increased dramatically.

35. The success of the high-yield varieties is indicated by the speed with which they have spread across the developing world. It has been estimated that between one-third and a half of the area devoted to rice in developing countries is now sown with them. CIAT (the International Centre for Tropical Agriculture, Colombia) estimated, for example, that in the mid-1980s high-yield varieties were grown on 90% of the 3 million hectares devoted to rice in Latin America. At present, nearly all modern crop varieties and some highly productive livestock strains contain genetic material recently incorporated from related wild or weedy species, or from more primitive genetic stocks still used and maintained by communities that practice traditional agricultural.

36. The combined economic value of the improvements in agricultural techniques has been significant in many parts of the world. In upland rice areas, for example, CIAT (1981) estimates that yield increases are between one ton/ha on irrigated areas and 0.75 tons/ha. This constitutes an annual increase of about 2.75 million tons of rice, which at an average price of $200/ton is an increase in the value of production of approximately $550 million. It has been estimated that at least half of the increase in agricultural productivity realised this century is directly attributable to "artificial selection, recombination and intraspecific gene transfer procedures" (Woodruff and Gall 1992).

37. A considerable amount of work has been carried out in estimating the often substantial value of genetic improvements to crops. Some of the more important studies are summarised in Table 2.

Table 2. Genetic diversity and agriculture: genetic contributions of cultivars to crop yields

CROP LOCATION PERIOD EFFECT ON PRODUCTION SOURCE

All crops USA 1980s $1.0 billion/year OTA, 1987, USDA est.
Maize USA 1930-80 2 of a four-fold increase in yields OTA, 1987 USA 1930-80 89% of yield gain of 103 kg/ha/yr
in commercials Duvick, 1984 USA 1930-80 71% of yield gains in single-cross hybrids Duvick, 1984 USA 1985-89 Genetic gains to N. Dakota of $2.3 million/year Frohberg, 1991 Rice Asia GR $1.5 billion/year Walgate, CALP USA 1930-80 2 of a doubling in yields OTA, 1987 Wheat Asia GR $2.0 billion/year Walgate, CALP USA 1930-80 2 of a doubling in yields OTA, 1987
USA 1958-80 0.74% genetic gain per year -
2 of 32% yield gain Schmidt, 1984 UK 1947-75 50% of an 84% gain in yields Silvey, 1978 World 1970-83 43% of genetic gain totalling 46% (best data) Kuhr et al., 1985 55% of genetic gain totalling 32% (all sites) Kuhr et al., 1985 Sorghum USA 1930-80 2 of a four-fold increase in yields OTA, 1987
1950-80 1-2% genetic gain per year from manipulating Miller and
Kebede, 1984 kernel numbers, plant weight, height and leaf area
Barley USA 1930-80 2 of a doubling in yields OTA, 1987
Potato USA 1930-80 2 of a four-fold increase in yields OTA, 1987 Soybeans USA 1930-80 2 of a doubling in yields OTA, 1987
USA 1902-77 79% of 23.7 kg/ha annual yield gains Specht and
Williams, 1984 Pearl Millet India at present genetic improvements worth $200 million
annually ICRISAT, 1990 Cotton USA 1930-80 2 of a doubling in yields OTA, 1987
1910-80 0.75% genetic gain per year Meredith, Jr and
Bridge, 1984
Sugar cane USA 1930-80 2 of a doubling in yields OTA, 1987 Tomato USA 1930-80 2 of a three-fold increase in yield OTA, 1987

38. The aggregate value of the raw genetic materials used in crop-breeding can also be ascertained by reference to the industry's spending on research and development. This is because, as with so many of the facets of biodiversity, the value of genetic variety for crop breeding lies in the potential value of future finds from the existing genetic stock. An indication of this value is given by the returns realised from past efforts at developing the previously existing gene pool for commercial use, as well as by the amounts currently being invested in such efforts.

39. The top 25 agricultural biotechnology -- or crop-breeding -- firms spent $330 million on research and development in 1988 (Hobbelink 1991). Crop breeding has generated a large return in the past -- US public and private expenditures on corn research totalled $100 million in 1984, contrasted with an estimated return of $190 million (Huffman and Evenson 1991). Such investments serve to pay for the development of both successful and unsuccessful varieties. It is estimated that, on average, 75% of new varieties recoup research and development costs (Olsen et al. 1996).

40. These figures indicate that the plants that are most closely related to our domesticated crops provide enormous benefits. Several important examples are given in Table 3. These varieties represent only a fraction of existing genetic diversity, but are probably some of the most valuable species on account of the ease of their introduction into mass production.

Table 3. Genetic diversity and agriculture: specific contributions made by wild relatives of crops

Crop Found in Effect on production

Wheat Turkey Genetic resistance to disease, valued at $50 million per year

Rice India Wild strain proved resistant to the grassy stunt virus

Barley Ethiopia Protects California's $160 million per year crop from yellow dwarf virus.

Beans Mexico Genes from the Mexican bean used to improve resistance to the Mexican bean weevil, which destroys as much as 25% of stored beans in Africa and 15% in South America.

Grapes Texas Texas rootstock used to revitalise the European wine industry in the 1860s after a louse infection.

Source: WCMC (1992)

41. For several reasons, however, the calculated value-gains from crop-breeding efforts are not equivalent to the value of the raw genetic material that exists in the wild. Such gains, for example, may be achieved using raw materials from a variety of sources: existing cultivated varieties (cultivars), varieties husbanded by traditional farmers (landraces), wild relatives of crops, or even -- with the advent of genetic engineering -- completely unrelated species. Furthermore, these gains must be apportioned among a number of factors that, together with these raw genetic materials, generate this increased value, including scientific effort, technology and commercial development.

42. Evaluating the sources of germplasm is a complex issue given the fact that once wild genetic material is incorporated into existing varieties, only the new variety has to be accessed in the future in order to develop further varieties. In other words, the contribution of wild genetic material is constantly reused although this is not reflected in the sources of germplasm. Table 4 shows the results of a survey of plant breeders about their sources of germplasm.

43. The sources of germplasm range from the already heavily exploited cultivars to completely wild species, to technologically altered species (biotechnology and induced mutation). Table 4 demonstrates that, averaged over a five-year period, 6.5% of all "successful" genetic research (i.e., research resulting in a marketed innovation) within the agricultural industry was focused on germplasm from relatively unknown species (wild species and landraces); 3% of such genetic research was directed to the transference of traits into the commercial system from wholly wild species.

Table 4. Source of germplasm used for all development of new varieties.

CROP GROUP

Source of Germplasm All Potatoes Cereals Oil Vegetable

Commercial cultivar 81.5 50.0 87.0 78.8 95.7

Related minor crop * 1.4 8.0 0.6 1.2 0.3

Wild species - ex situ gene bank 2.5 19.0 1.2 1.0 1.4

Wild species - maintained in situ 1.0 0.0 0.7 0.1 0.1

Landrace - ex situ gene bank 1.6 1.7 1.7 2.3 1.7

Landrace - maintained in situ 1.4 0.0 0.7 2.8 0.4

Induced mutation 2.2 3.3 0.7 7.2 0.3

Biotechnology 4.5 17.7 3.5 6.8 0.1

Source: WCMC 1994. (Note that all columns are percentages, but that not all columns sum to 100% as some innovations defied categorisation under a single source). [* "related minor crop": minor crop cultivated on a small scale with some improvement over wild ancestors]

44. One other important indicator derived from the table is the extent to which substitutes exist for external supplies of new germplasm. There is only one alternative at present: induced mutation. This technological approach to generating diversity supplies about 2.2% of new germplasm, approximately one-third as important as natural sources. The other important contributor, biotechnology, is not so much a substitute for natural diversity as it is a method for transferring characteristics across greater distances (i.e., between less closely related species). New biotechnological methods for transporting germplasm provide about 4.5% of all germplasm, but it is very likely that biotechnological research relies upon natural diversity to the same extent that general agricultural research does.

45. The value of the wild species multiplies if the dynamic nature of the battle against pests is considered as well. For example, Chang (1989a, in Evenson 1995) reports that while resistance to whitebacked planthoppers was found in only 0.8% of the 48,544 varieties of Q. sativa screened at IRRI, it was found in 46.2% of the 437 wild Oryza species tested. While the development of a particular pest resistance can take a decade, it can take as little as 4 or 5 years for the resistance to "break down" as pathogens and pests evolve far more quickly (Olsen et al. 1996), thereby creating the need for the continuous development of new varieties.

46. Evenson (1995) calculated a breeding production function for rice that allows for an estimate of the role of the size of the crop genetic resources entering the research and development process. According to his results, the increase of catalogued accessions from around 20,000 to 60,000 between 1960 and 1995 has been responsible for 20% of the gains in yield. These estimates suggests that each additional rice genetic resource accessions adds, on average, between US$2,500 to US$5,000 per year in perpetuity. The present value of this stream, assuming a ten-year lag -- the time needed to develop and market a variety -- and a 10% discount rate is $10,000 and $20,000 (Evenson 1995).

4. Conclusion

47. The existing literature clearly demonstrates that genetic diversity is the source of considerable wealth and, consequently, is extremely valuable.

Advice on the economic valuation of biological diversity is of general relevance to the three-fold objectives of the Convention and, as a consequence, any recommendations made by the SBSTTA can be of relevance to other items to be considered by the COP, including items 6, 7, 9, 12 and 14 of the provisional agenda. For example, item 12 is to consider the possible options for implementing Article 15 on access to genetic resources. Clearly, developing effective strategies will depend on an understanding of the economic value of these genetic resources.

48. The research carried out so far has been ad hoc and suffers from a lack of rigorous and reliable methodologies. A number of areas have been the subject of some attention, but many other uses of genetic diversity have not received any attention at all. For example, even direct uses of the informational value of genetic diversity in areas such as: enzyme development by industries (see UNEP/CBD/SBSTTA/2/14); the agricultural use of animals; or the use in horticulture have received little or no attention at all. Other more indirect benefits, such as the role that genetic diversity plays in supporting the more strategic benefits of biodiversity in general -- climate stability or watershed functions, for example -- have not been considered at all. Moreover, the rapid developments of new applications for these resources makes the existing data even less complete.

49. Methodological problems also raise questions about the veracity and usefulness of much of the data that have been collected so far. As demonstrated in this Note, all of the studies carried out so far have used definitions and methodologies that have not been universally accepted, neither could they be considered as providing a reliable basis on which to implement the provision of the Convention. For example, defining the contribution that naturally occurring genetic resources make to research and development in the pharmaceutical industry has proven problematic. Indeed, differing definitions of the contribution made by naturally occurring genes has allowed researchers simultaneously to conclude that NPR is both decreasing and increasing.

50. Current understanding of this issue can therefore at best only be considered as piecemeal and anecdotal. It certainly is not possible to approximate even to a rudimentary level where, how and to what extent genetic diversity is used; let alone understand the value of that use. Such a situation does not provide a very sound basis for decision-making, and also means that there are likely to exist significant externalities and that genetic resources are not likely to be properly managed.

51. Efforts to gather more information, or empirical data, have been hampered by factors such as: (a) a suspicion about the purpose and utility of attempts to gather this information within industries that use genetic diversity; (b) confidentiality problems arising from the commercially sensitive nature of some of this information; (c) lack of resources on behalf of those undertaking the research; and (d) a lack of co-ordination and use of existing sources of information.

52. The needs of the Convention require a reliable understanding of the value of those genetic resources that are utilised and of genetic diversity in general. It is clear that there still does not exist enough information on the value of genetic resources for the needs of the Convention, neither is there a sufficiently reliable methodology for estimating the value of these resources.

53. A first step to fulfilling these needs would be to undertake a more thorough and extensive effort to collect existing empirical data on the value of genetic resources than has been possible for the preparation of this Note. As is evident in this Note, many other processes collect relevant data and have to some degree developed methodologies for estimating the economic value of genetic resources. To some extent, the collection of these data may be facilitated by the establishment of the clearing-house mechanism. However, there is extensive empirical data with international organisations and private institutions that will not be accessible through this mechanism. Important international organisations and processes in this regard are the FAO; the CGIAR; CABI, the WFCC and the IDAs established under the 1977 Budapest Treaty (see inf doc for COP/3); and the international intellectual property regime under the auspices of WIPO. Because of the nature of such an exercise it would provide a good opportunity for developing co-operation with these processes and would also contribute to the implementation of decision II/13 of the COP.

54. The data held by private interests, the main users of genetic diversity, will not be directly accessible through the clearing-house mechanism. Moreover, these interests have, in the past, not seen the sense of developing this area. It is important that these concerns be addressed and any misconceptions dispelled so that all stakeholders are included in the process.

55. Any consideration given to the mechanism for collecting such data needs to recognise that this exercise will only provide the necessary information for the needs of the Convention if it is carried continuously and over a period of years. Short projects of limited duration will not materially address the needs of the Convention and will only add to the ad hoc nature of the existing information.

56. Due to the breadth of the subject matter and the limited resources available to tackle the needs of the Convention, an obvious strategy for making the work of the SBSTTA effective in the short term is to focus its efforts in a limited number of areas. The SBSTTA may wish, therefore, to identify one or more areas to which special emphasis might be given. Naturally, any selection needs to be guided by the existing knowledge base, its relevance to other areas being considered by the COP and the SBSTTA, and the needs of the Parties. Such areas are not confined to the matter of access to genetic resources, but, as noted in Section 2 of this Note, also include identifying important components of biological diversity as required by Article 7, in particular the development of criteria for identifying, assessing and monitoring processes and activities that have an adverse impact on biological diversity, implementing Articles 10 and 11 with regard to incentives, and developing procedures for environmental-impact assessments. Alternatively, the SBSTTA may wish to consider emphasising a particular topic in order to support its thematic approach in general. For example, it may wish to emphasise this work in regard to marine and coastal biological diversity (see document UNEP/CBD/SBSTTA/2/15) or some other theme in preparation for future meetings, or as a result of this meeting, for example, agricultural biological diversity.

57. The lack of data and methodologies points to a need for further research both at the applied -- case study -- level and at the theoretical level. Obviously, undertaking this exercise is beyond the capacity of the SBSTTA or any other institution of the Convention. Consequently, the SBSTTA may wish to consider how it might best encourage this research in line with Article 12 of the Convention. The SBSTTA may wish to consider how it can draw on on-going academic research and conferences and present to the COP on a regular basis a review of the state of knowledge, for example, as a follow-up to the Global Biodiversity Assessment's work.

58. These factors point to the need for and benefit to the SBSTTA of considering some intercessional activity to best guide the on-going activities of the many other actors needed to be involved in developing the necessary methodologies and collecting information and data. They would then be able to contribute to meetings of the SBSTTA the type of information required for specific topics and more generally to develop specific areas that have the greatest potential for contributing to the aims of the Convention. The SBSTTA may also wish to consider a recommendation to the COP that, given the need for considerable development of the issue, the matter be included as a standing item on the agenda of future meetings of the SBSTTA and/or the COP.

References

Albers­Schonberg, G. 1995. "The Pharmaceutical Discovery Process" in T. Swanson (ed.) 1995. Intellectual Property Rights and Biodiversity Conservation, Cambridge University Press: Cambridge.

Alyward, B The Economic Value of Pharmaceutical Prospecting and its Role in Biodiversity Conservation (LEEC Paper DP 93-05).

Arrow, K. 1962. "Economic Welfare and the Allocation of Resources for Invention", in R. Nelson (ed.) The Rate and Direction of Inventive Activity, Harvard University Press: Cambridge.

Falconer, J. 1990. The Major Significance of `minor' forest products: The local use and value of forests in the West African humid forest zone. Community forestry note 6, FAO, Rome.

Lewington, A. (1993). Medicinal Plants and Plant Extracts: A review of their importation into Europe, A Traffic Network Report, TRAFFIC International, Cambridge.

Okigbo, B.N. 1983. Fruits and vegetable production and extension services in Africa. Acta horticulture, 123:23-27.

Olsen, N., T. Swanson, and H. Gillett. 1996. The Use of Plant Genetic Resources in Agriculture, in Swanson and Luxmoore, op. cit.

Orians,G., G. Brown, W. Kunin, and J. Swierzbinski (eds.). 1990. The Preservation and Valuation of Biological Resources, University of Washington Press: Seattle.

Perrings (ed.) 1995. The Economic Value of Biodiversity, in Heywood (ed.) op. cit.

Ruitenbeck, J. 1989. Social cost-benefit analysis of the Korup Project, Cameroon, prepared for the World Wide Fund for Nature and the Republic of Cameroon, London.

Sayer, J.A. 1991. Using non-timber products to support forest conservation programmes, pp 39-48, in ITTO, Status and Potential of Non-timber products in the Sustainable Development of Tropical Forests, Yokohama, Japan

Stoneman, P. 1983. The Economic Analysis of Technological Change, Oxford University Press: Oxford.

Swanson, T. (ed.) 1995. Intellectual Property Rights and Biodiversity Conservation, Cambridge University Press: Cambridge.

WCMC. 1992. Global Biodiversity: status of the Earth's living resources. Chapman and Hall: London.

Woodruff, D.S. and G.A.E. Gall. 1992. Genetics and conservation. Agriculture, Ecosystems and Environment. 42:53-73. CIAT 1981. Report on the Fourth IRTP Conference in Latin America, Cali.

Duvick, D.N. 1984. Genetic contributions to yield gains of U.S. hybrid maize, 1930 to 1980. In: W.R. Fehr (ed.), Genetic Contributions to Yield Gains of Five Major Crop Plants. Crop Science Society of America, Special Publication 7: Madison. Pp.15-47.

Frohberg, R.C. 1991. Economic impact of plant breeding programs. Farm Research 48:3-8.

Hobbelink, H. 1991. Biotechnology and the Future of World Agriculture. Zed Books: London.

Huffman, W.E. and R.E. Evenson. 1991. Science for agriculture. Department of Economics, Iowa State University: Ames. Mimeo.

ICRISAT 1990. ICRISAT's Contribution to Pearl Millet Production. ICRISAT, Cereals Program, Andhra Pradesh.

Kuhr, S.L., V.A. Johnson, C.J. Peterson, and P.J. Mattern. 1985. Trends in winter wheat performance as measured in international trials. Crop Science 25:1045-1049.

Meredith, W.R. Jr and R.R. Bridge. 1984. Genetic contributions to yield changes in upland cotton. In: W.R. Fehr (ed.), Genetic Contributions to Yield Gains of Five Major Crop Plants. Crop Science Society of America, Special Publication 7: Madison. Pp.75-87.

Miller, F.R. and Y. Kebede. 1984. Genetic contributions to yield gains in sorghum, 1950 to 1980. In: W.R. Fehr (ed.) Genetic Contributions to Yield Gains of Five Major Crop Plants. Crop Science Society of America, Special Publication 7: Madison. Pp.1­13.

OTA 1987. Technologies to Maintain Biological Diversity. OTA­F­330. U.S. Government Printing Office, Washington.

Schmidt, J.W. 1984. Genetic contributions to yield gains in wheat. In: W.R. Fehr (ed.) Genetic Contributions to Yield Gains of Five Major Crop Plants. Crop Science Society of America, Special Publication 7: Madison. Pp.89-101.

Silvey, V. 1978. The contribution of new varieties to increasing cereal yield in England and Wales. Journal of the National Institute of Agricultural Botany 14:367-384.

Specht, J.W. and J.H. Williams. 1984. Contributions of genetic technology to soybean productivity - retrospect prospect. In: W.R. Fehr (ed.), Genetic Contributions to Yield Gains of Five Major Crop Plants. Crop Science Society of America, Special Publication 7: Madison. Pp.15-73.